********************************************************    
                         NOTICE
********************************************************

This document was converted from
WordPerfect or Word to ASCII Text format.

Content from the original version of the document such as
headers, footers, footnotes, endnotes, graphics, and page numbers
will not show up in this text version.

All text attributes such as bold, italic, underlining, etc. from the
original document will not show up in this text version.

Features of the original document layout such as
columns, tables, line and letter spacing, pagination, and margins
will not be preserved in the text version.

If you need the complete document, download the
WordPerfect version or Adobe Acrobat version, if available.

*****************************************************************
                                Before the
                      Federal Communications Commission
                          Washington, D.C. 20554

     

In the Matter of                        )
                                     )
Fees for Ancillary or Supplementary               )         MM Docket No. 97-247
Use of Digital Television Spectrum           )
Pursuant to Section 336(e)(1) of the         )
Telecommunications Act of 1996          )
                                     

                  MEMORANDUM OPINION AND ORDER


   Adopted:  November 19, 1999          Released:  November 24, 1999

By the Commission:


                             I.  INTRODUCTION

     1.  In our Report and Order in this proceeding, we implemented Section 201 of the Telecommunications
Act of 1996 ("1996 Act") which adopted Section 336 of the Communications Act of 1934, requiring broadcast
television licensees to pay a fee if they provide certain types of ancillary or supplementary services on their digital
television ("DTV") bitstream.  Based on the criteria set forth in Section 201, we adopted rules to require DTV
licensees to pay a fee of five percent of the gross revenues received from the provision of such "feeable" ancillary or
supplementary services.  We also provided guidance on which services are subject to this fee and specifically
concluded that home shopping, infomercial, and direct marketing services would not be feeable.

     2.  We have received two petitions asking us to reconsider aspects of the Report and Order.  The National
Association of Broadcasters and the Association for Maximum Service Television have filed a joint petition (the
"NAB/MSTV Petition") asking us to set the fee at two percent of gross revenues rather than five percent.  The
Office of Communication Inc. of the United Church of Christ, the Benton Foundation, the Center for Media
Education, the Civil Rights Forum and Media Access Project have filed a joint petition (the "UCC, et al. Petition")
asking us to hold that home shopping, infomercials, and direct marketing services are subject to fees.  We deny both
petitions for reconsideration.
                               II.  BACKGROUND

     3.  Pursuant to the 1996 Act, the Commission has assigned each existing broadcast television station an
additional channel to convert to digital technology.  We are requiring broadcasters to provide on their DTV bitstream
at least one over-the-air video program signal at no direct charge to viewers.   Aside from this requirement, we have
given broadcasters great flexibility in the services they provide over their DTV bitstream.  They may offer a wide
range of ancillary or supplementary services such as computer software distribution, data transmission, teletext,
interactive materials, aural messages, paging services, audio signals, and subscription video.

     4.  The 1996 Act requires broadcasters to pay a fee to the U.S. Treasury to the extent they use their DTV
bitstream to provide ancillary or supplementary services --

          (A) for which the payment of a subscription fee is required in order to receive such services, or

          (B)  for which the licensee directly or indirectly receives compensation from a third party in return
     for transmitting material furnished by such a third party (other than commercial advertisements
     used to support broadcasting for which a subscription fee is not required).

The 1996 Act directed the Commission to establish a program to assess and collect this fee based on the following
three objectives:

             "to recover for the public a portion of the value of the public spectrum resource made available
     for such commercial use";

             "to avoid unjust enrichment through the method employed to permit such uses of that resource";

             to "recover for the public an amount that, to the extent feasible, equals but does not exceed (over
     the term of the license) the amount that would have been recovered had such services been licensed
     pursuant to [the competitive bidding process.]"

     5.  In the Report and Order, we established a fee program that requires broadcasters to pay a fee of five
percent of the gross revenues they receive from feeable ancillary or supplementary services offered on their DTV
bitstream.  We reasoned that this fee is consistent with the three objectives set forth in the Act.  It also represented
a reasonable fee in light of the record in the proceeding, in which some parties argued for a very low or nominal fee
and others for a fee of more than ten percent.

     III.  THE NAB/MSTV PETITION

     6.  NAB/MSTV argue that we failed to consider two studies they submitted that they believe call for a fee
of two percent of gross revenues rather than five percent.  The first study, prepared by Jerry Hausman, purports to
establish "the low and declining value of comparable spectrum," and also that digital ancillary or supplementary
services "face significant business and technological uncertainty."  The second study, prepared by Kent Anderson,
describes several surveys of technology licensing fees in the private sector.  According to NAB/MSTV, the two
studies support a lower fee under the statutory criteria, one of which requires that the fee be designed to recover an
amount that approximates, to the extent feasible, the revenues that would have been received had the spectrum on
which these services are provided been licensed through an auction.  The Association of Local Television Stations
("ALTV") submitted comments supporting the NAB/MSTV Petition.  The National Cable Television Association
("NCTA") filed an opposition to the petition.

     7.  Contrary to NAB/MSTV's suggestion, we did consider the two studies in reaching our decision in the
Report and Order.  Indeed, consistent with a recommendation in the Hausman Study, we declined to impose an
upfront or hybrid fee on DTV licensees that provide feeable services.  Although we rejected arguments based on
the two studies to set the fee lower than five percent, we explained in paragraphs 28-29 of the Report and Order our
reasons for doing so.  We reaffirm this decision and amplify our reasons below.

     8.  We turn to the Anderson Study first.  The Anderson Study describes several surveys of royalty rates
used in licensing various technologies in the private sector.  Although we did not cite the Anderson Study explicitly
and our discussion of the issue was brief, the Report and Order, at  29, did reject arguments that we should set a
lower fee based on analogies to copyright royalty rates.  We declined to do so because the policy concerns and
economic considerations involved in setting a fee for ancillary or supplementary services appear to be different from
the considerations involved in negotiations over private licensing rights.  We have more closely examined the
Anderson Study and are not persuaded that we should alter our decision.  Indeed, the Anderson Study itself
acknowledges that "[e]ach licensing negotiation has unique characteristics, making it very difficult to demonstrate
that the royalty observed for any one licensing agreement reasonably applies to another."  This statement confirms
our reluctance in the Report and Order to directly base the fee required under Section 336(e) on analogies to private
licensing arrangements.

     9.  Aside from this concern, the Anderson Study can actually be read to support a fee of five percent of
gross revenues.  The NAB/MSTV Petition, at 5, argues that the Anderson Study "found that licensing rates for
unproven technologies without 'highly favorable economics' tended to be very low."  But the full sentence in the
Anderson Study that is cited to support this statement states: "For 'minor' innovations the range [of running royalty
rates] is 1 to 5 percent, and for 'major' innovations it is 3 to 8 percent.  Only in the case of innovations characterized
as 'revolutionary' (i.e., suggesting highly favorable economics) do the rates rise to the 5 to 10 percent range."  The
five percent fee we have established thus falls somewhere in the middle of these reported ranges and could even be
characterized as falling within the range of royalty rates for "minor innovations."  More generally, Anderson
summarizes the overall results of his research as "show[ing] that some technologies earn royalties on the order of 2
to 3 percent or less, most earn royalties of 5 percent or less, and only those technologies with unusually favorable
economics receive rates of more than 10 percent."  Again, this places a five percent fee squarely in the average
range, which we believe is reasonable.  This is especially the case since we are not imposing an upfront or hybrid fee
on DTV licensees.  By comparison, a fair number of the royalty arrangements described in the Anderson Study
appear to involve upfront payments in addition to royalty fees.  Taking these upfront payments into account
suggests that the five percent fee we have established may actually fall toward the low end of the total licensing
payments (royalties plus upfront fees) surveyed in the Anderson Study.

     10.  We now turn to the Hausman Study.  Based on an econometric study of the FCC's previous auctions,
Hausman reports that prices for spectrum auctioned by the Commission have been decreasing over time on a per
megahertz per population basis.  He also posits that there will be significant sunk cost investments required to
provide DTV ancillary or supplementary services, and also significant business and technological uncertainty facing
these services.  Hausman concludes that "the combination of overall declining auction results over time and the
significant business and technological uncertainty with respect to sunk costs would lead to an expected outcome of
relatively low auction results for spectrum used for ancillary services."  Noting that the Notice had sought comment
on setting the fee in the range of one to ten percent, Hausman recommends "that the Commission initially begin with
a fee toward the low end of the range."

     11.  As an initial matter, we question a number of the underlying assertions made in the Hausman Study. 
Even assuming it is true that there is a downward trend in per megahertz, per population prices for the spectrum
auctions the Commission has previously held, this does not necessarily mean that an auction of the spectrum used
for DTV ancillary or supplementary services would follow this trend.  As we stated in the Report and Order, at 
28, the auction values realized by the Commission in conducting a particular spectrum auction reflect factors that
are specific to the particular spectrum being auctioned.  These factors include the anticipated demand for the
telecommunications services provided using the particular spectrum and the technological uncertainty associated
with the application.  The Report and Order pointed to evidence that suggests that the broadcast spectrum that will
be used to provide DTV ancillary or supplementary services could command higher prices than predicted by the
trend described in the Hausman Study.  In particular, we noted that the sales values of broadcast properties have
increased sharply over the past several years, reflecting the increasing value of their spectrum licenses.  The
NAB/MSTV Petition faults the Report and Order for focusing on this evidence and for not placing greater weight
on the value of non-broadcast spectrum because most ancillary or supplementary services will be non-broadcast in
nature.  But we think it is reasonable to expect that the prices investors pay for television stations reflect not only
the anticipated profits from providing broadcast video programming on the station but also the projected profits from
"non-broadcast" ancillary or supplementary services that they can now provide on the station's DTV bitstream.  The
recent sales prices for television stations thus shed some light on the value of the spectrum used to provide the
ancillary or supplementary services.  Indeed, Hausman himself has previously testified before Congress that station
sale prices provide a reasonable proxy for the value of the spectrum they use.

     12.  In addition, we question the Hausman Study's assertions regarding the degree of uncertainty and sunk
costs DTV licensees will face in providing ancillary or supplementary services.  Whether or not they choose to
provide ancillary or supplementary services, DTV licensees will need to invest in DTV facilities in order to provide
a free, over-the-air digital broadcast service.  Given this, it would appear that the incremental or marginal cost of
providing any feeable ancillary or supplementary services may not be as significant as Hausman and NAB/MSTV
suggest.  The most substantial costs incurred by broadcasters, such as transmitters and towers, will be sunk or fixed
costs that are already incurred in connection with the provision of nonfeeable services, thus minimizing the additional
investment required to provide feeable services.  We consequently agree with NCTA that the risk associated with
offering ancillary or supplementary services will be diminished by the fact that DTV licensees will be providing
nonfeeable broadcast services.

     13.  We also think Hausman and NAB/MSTV overstate the level of uncertainty broadcasters face in
developing ancillary or supplementary services.  We fully recognize developing and implementing these services will
entail challenges and risks.  But broadcasters are not venturing into completely uncharted territory.  They have been
authorized to provide ancillary services on parts of their analog signals for years, although these services have been
limited due to the lack of capacity on analog channels.  Broadcasters have also become increasingly involved over
the years in developing and selling programming carried on cable networks, and they can translate this experience
into providing subscription programming over their DTV bitstream should that appear profitable to them.  More
recently, a number of broadcasters have invested in internet-related companies, suggesting that the internet's
interactive and datacasting applications, which potentially could also be offered over the DTV bitstream, may prove
profitable.  There are risks, to be sure, but knowledgeable people inside and outside broadcasting confidently
anticipate innovative and gainful pursuits over the DTV bitstream.

     14.  Aside from the questions we have about some of the Hausman Study's underlying assertions, we have
a more fundamental objection to the conclusion NAB/MSTV seek to draw from it.  In particular, neither
NAB/MSTV nor Hausman provides a persuasive basis to conclude that Hausman's assertions, even taken at face
value, require us to set the fee at two percent rather than five percent of gross revenues. The Hausman Study seems
to acknowledge this in that it has no firm recommendation on the level of the fee, only suggesting that the FCC
initially set the fee "toward the low end of the range" and that the Commission "might consider" initially setting the
fee at one percent or less.  For its part, the NAB/MSTV Petition argues that the studies it has submitted "provide[]
strong support for the Commission to set a low initial fee" and concludes that the fee should be two percent of gross
revenues, yet it provides no rationale why a "low fee" necessarily means a fee of two percent as opposed to five
percent.

     15.  We continue to think that a fee of five percent of gross revenues is reasonable in light of the criteria set
forth in Section 336(e).  A central theme underlying NAB/MSTV's arguments and the studies they have submitted
is that we should set the fee so as not "to discourage the development of new ancillary and supplementary services"
and to "promote[] the efficient use of digital spectrum."  We agree that this is a worthy goal and, indeed, Section
1 of the Communications Act states that one of the Act's purposes is to promote an "efficient" radio communication
service.  But this general policy cannot trump the specific statutory criteria set forth in Section 336(e)(2) for
establishing the fee, none of which require that the fee be designed to maximize efficiency.  Indeed, taken to its
logical conclusion, the goal of maximizing efficiency and encouraging ancillary or supplementary services would
mean that the fee should be set at zero or some nominal percentage rate as this would eliminate any influence the fee
would have on a DTV licensee's decision to provide ancillary or supplementary services as opposed to nonfeeable
broadcast video programming.  But clearly this is not what Congress intended.  A fee system that raised no or only
nominal revenue from licensees that provide "feeable" ancillary or supplementary services would (quite literally)
make Congress's enactment of Section 336(e) all for naught.

     16.  In the end, implementing Section 336(e) is not, to paraphrase one of the parties, an exact science. 
NAB/MSTV acknowledge that the Commission has "broad discretion under the Act in setting the fee level."  In
exercising this discretion, we have sought to promote the efficient use of the spectrum and the development of
innovative ancillary or supplementary services by DTV licensees.  But this discretion is bounded by Section 336(e),
which requires us to design the fee not only to approximate the revenue that would have been received had these
services been licensed through an auction, but also to recover a portion of the value of the spectrum used for these
services and avoid "unjust enrichment" of DTV licensees who have been given the exclusive right to apply for DTV
channels without having to bid for them at an auction.  Weighing these factors and the comments submitted in the
proceeding -- some of which argued for a fee of less than one percent while others argued for a fee of over ten
percent -- we established a fee of five percent of gross revenues generated from feeable ancillary or supplementary
services.  The amount raised by this fee will vary with the gross revenues from these services, i.e., with the
willingness of consumers to pay for such services.  As a consequence, if the consumer value for these services is low,
the fee payment will be small.  Given this, and the record in this proceeding and the criteria set forth in Section
336(e), we continue to believe this is a reasonable fee and consistent with the statute, and therefore deny the
NAB/MSTV Petition.


                        IV.  THE UCC, et al. PETITION

     17.  In the Report and Order, at  40, we decided not to impose fees on revenues received from home
shopping, infomercial or direct marketing services.  We reasoned that

          [t]he purpose of this proceeding is not to exact fees from existing broadcasters for existing services
     but, rather, to design a program for the assessment of fees on ancillary or supplementary services
     which will be provided on the DTV bitstream.  We agree with the commenters who argued that
     home shopping and infomercials are commercial advertisements, excluded by statute from the
     scope of ancillary and supplementary services as they are video services received by viewers
     without a fee.  [Footnote omitted.]  We therefore find that home shopping channels and
     infomercials are free, over-the-air television services, supported by commercial advertisements,
     and not subject to a fee.

     18.  UCC, et al. ask the Commission to reconsider this decision.  They interpret the 1996 Act as requiring
us to impose fees on home shopping, infomercial, and direct marketing services.  NAB, MSTV, ALTV, and Home
Shopping Network ("HSN") and ValueVision International ("ValueVision") have opposed UCC, et al.'s petition for
reconsideration and argue that the Commission was correct in concluding that these services are not subject to fees.

     19.  UCC, et al. interpret the Report and Order as basing this conclusion on two rationales:  (1) that home
shopping, infomercials, and direct marketing services are "existing" services, and therefore grandfathered from the
fee requirements in the Act; and (2) that these services are "commercial advertisements" rather than programming
services, and consequently fall within Section 336(e)(1)(B), which exempts from fees "commercial advertisements
used to support broadcasting for which a subscription fee is not required."  As to the first rationale, UCC, et al.
argue that the 1996 Act does not give the Commission authority to grandfather existing services from the new
statutory fee requirements.  As to the second rationale, UCC, et al. maintain that it is arbitrary and capricious to
categorize home shopping and similar services as "commercial advertisements" exempt under Section 336(e)(1)(B)
because Congress, the Commission, and the broadcast industry have consistently characterized these services as
programming not as commercial advertisements.

     20.  We think UCC, et al. have misconstrued the Report and Order on these points.  Our decision was not
intended to grandfather existing services.  Nor was it based on whether home shopping and similar services should
be categorized as "commercial advertisements" or "programming."  We recognize that the Report and Order, at 
40, may have been unclear on this point in that it referred to these services as "commercial advertisements."  But we
did not intend this characterization to be the basis for our decision not to impose fees on these services.  Rather, we
based this decision on what we see as a threshold criterion in the statute: only ancillary or supplementary services
are subject to fees under the Act.  Because traditional home shopping, infomercial and direct marketing services are
free, over-the-air, video services and therefore do not qualify as ancillary or supplementary services as we have
defined that term in our rules, they are not subject to fees.  Or, as we put it in the Report and Order, at  40, these
services are "excluded by statute from the scope of ancillary and supplementary services as they are video services
received by viewers without a fee."  We take this opportunity to elaborate on this reasoning.

     21.  Section 336(e)(1), which defines the "services to which fees apply," speaks only in terms of "ancillary
or supplementary services" in delineating in subsections (A) and (B) the two types of such services that are subject
to fees.  In doing so, it necessarily excludes from the fees requirement services that are not "ancillary or
supplementary" to begin with.  Although the Act does not define the phrase "ancillary or supplementary services,"
the Commission did so in implementing Section 336 in its DTV rulemaking proceeding.  In that proceeding, we
adopted Section 73.624(c) of our rules, which provides an illustrative list of ancillary or supplementary
services:Brad BB  they include, but are not limited to, "computer software distribution, data transmissions, teletext,
interactive materials, aural messages, paging services, audio signals, subscription video, and any other services that
do not derogate DTV broadcast stations' obligations" to "transmit at least one over-the-air video program signal at
no direct charge to viewers."  Section 73.624(c) goes on to state "that any video broadcast signal provided at no
direct charge to viewers shall not be considered ancillary or supplementary."

     22.  Traditional home shopping, infomercial, or direct marketing services are video broadcast signals and
are offered at no direct charge to viewers.  As such, they fall outside the scope of our definition of "ancillary or
supplementary services," and therefore are not subject to fees under Section 336(e)(1) of the Act. We think this is
consistent with Congress's intent in enacting Section 336(e)(1).  To be sure, we adopted our definition of "ancillary
or supplementary services" after enactment of the 1996 Act.  But as HSN and ValueVision state, "the Act's specific
instruction that fees were to be assessed only on 'ancillary and supplementary' digital services was arrived at in the
context of the Commission's contemporaneous consideration of [its then pending DTV rulemaking proceeding], in
which the Commission repeatedly and consistently made clear that 'ancillary and supplementary' services are
separate and distinct from existing, traditional over-the-air broadcast services."  We believe Congress drew the
same distinction in enacting Section 336, excluding free, over-the-air broadcast video programming service from
fees.  Traditional home shopping, infomercials, and direct marketing services have long been a free, over-the-air
broadcast service, or, in Section 73.624(c)'s rubric, a "video broadcast signal provided at no direct charge to
viewers."  It follows that in enacting Section 336 Congress did not intend to include these existing services within the
phrase "ancillary or supplementary services" and subject them to fees.

     23.  Further evidence of this can be found in Section 336(b)(3), which states, among other things, that "no
ancillary or supplementary service shall have any rights to carriage under section 614 or 615," i.e., the statutory
"must carry" rights broadcast television stations have to be carried on cable systems in their local area.  If a free,
over-the-air home shopping broadcast service is considered an "ancillary or supplementary service," stations
carrying such programming would be rendered ineligible for must carry rights under Section 336(b)(3).  We do not
think Congress could have intended such a result given that, in Section 4(g) of the Cable Television Consumer
Protection and Competition Act of 1992 (the "1992 Cable Act"), it directed the FCC to determine whether home
shopping stations served the public interest and were entitled to must carry rights.  It would make little sense for
Congress to charge us with this duty, and then four years later preclude home shopping stations from must carry
rights under Section 336(b)(3) without a mention, either in the 1996 Act or its legislative history, of Section 4(g) of
the 1992 Cable Act.  A basic principal of statutory construction is to seek to construe statutory provisions so that
they are consistent with each other.  We think the most reasonable way to square Section 336 and Section 4(g) of
the 1992 Cable Act is not to treat traditional home shopping, infomercials, and direct marketing services as ancillary
or supplementary services.

     24.  We do not agree with UCC, et al.'s suggestion that our decision not to apply fees to home shopping,
infomercials and direct marketing services means any service provided without charge to the viewer is exempt from
fees regardless of whether a third party compensates a broadcaster for carriage.  Nor do we agree with UCC, et al.'s
argument that our decision effectively nullifies Section 336(e)(1)(B), which requires us to impose fees on ancillary
or supplementary services "for which the licensee directly or indirectly receives compensation from a third party in
return for transmitting material furnished by such third party (other than commercial advertisements used to support
broadcasting for which a subscription fee is not required)."  Our decision today does not exempt, for example,
payments made to a DTV licensee by a stock broker to transmit stock quote data to the broker's clients even though
the clients pay no direct fee for this service. This clearly would be an "ancillary or supplementary service" that is
feeable under Section 336(e)(1)(B).  

     25.  But where, as here, the service is a video broadcast signal provided at no direct charge to viewers, it is
not feeable, even though the broadcaster may be receiving compensation from a third party to carry the service.  As
HSN and ValueVision point out, to hold otherwise would mean that "all the affiliates of the ABC, CBS and NBC
broadcast television networks arguably would be subject to fees for their free, over-the-air broadcast services
because they receive compensation from their networks for airing network programming."  These are video
broadcast signals provided to viewers at no direct charge, and therefore are not ancillary or supplementary services
and are not subject to fees.  We consequently deny UCC, et al.'s Petition.

     26.  We make one final note.  Our decision in the Report and Order, like our decision today, applies only
to traditional home shopping, infomercials, direct marketing and similar services with no interactive or "clickable"
elements and which can entail viewers purchasing products by calling a telephone number identified during the
broadcast.  We recognize that it may be possible in the future for these purchases to be made via an interactive
system provided by the licensee on its DTV bitstream.  For example, a DTV viewer may be able to purchase a
product shown on a home shopping program by clicking a special icon displayed on the screen and transmitting a
purchase order via the licensee's DTV bitstream.  In reply comments submitted in the initial round of comments of
this proceeding, ValueVision and HSN stated that such an interactive purchase order system was being explored and
argued that revenues generated from this sort of system should be exempt from fees.  Because such services are
only at a nascent stage and the particular circumstances are unclear at this point, we decline to decide whether they
would constitute an ancillary or supplementary service subject to a fee under Section 336(e)(1)(B).


                          V. ADMINISTRATIVE MATTERS

     27.  The action contained herein has been analyzed with respect to the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995
and found to impose no new or modified reporting and record-keeping requirements or burdens on the public.  In
addition, the Final Regulatory Flexibility Act Analysis set forth in the Report and Order in this proceeding remains
unchanged.

     28.  ACCORDINGLY, IT IS ORDERED that, pursuant to the authority granted by 47 U.S.C.  4(i),
303, 336(e), and 47 C.F.R.  1.429, the Petition for Reconsideration filed jointly by the National Association of
Broadcasters and the Association for Maximum Service Television, and the Petition for Reconsideration 
filed jointly by the Office of Communication Inc. of the United Church of Christ, the Benton Foundation, the Center
for Media Education, the Civil Rights Forum and Media Access Project, are both hereby DENIED.
     
     29.  IT IS FURTHER ORDERED that this proceeding IS TERMINATED.

     .
                         FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION



                         Magalie Roman Salas
                         Secretary